for Journals by Title or ISSN
for Articles by Keywords
help
  Subjects -> AGRICULTURE (Total: 721 journals)
    - AGRICULTURAL ECONOMICS (71 journals)
    - AGRICULTURE (493 journals)
    - CROP PRODUCTION AND SOIL (91 journals)
    - DAIRYING AND DAIRY PRODUCTS (26 journals)
    - POULTRY AND LIVESTOCK (40 journals)

AGRICULTURE (493 journals)                  1 2 3 4 5 | Last

Aceh International Journal of Science and Technology     Open Access   (Followers: 1)
Acta agriculturae Slovenica     Open Access   (Followers: 5)
Acta Agrobotanica     Open Access   (Followers: 3)
Acta Agronomica Hungarica     Full-text available via subscription   (Followers: 1)
Acta Agronomica Sinica     Full-text available via subscription   (Followers: 6)
Acta Scientiarum. Animal Sciences     Open Access   (Followers: 2)
Acta Scientiarum. Technology     Open Access   (Followers: 1)
Acta Technologica Agriculturae     Open Access   (Followers: 3)
Advances in Agriculture     Open Access   (Followers: 2)
Advances in Agriculture & Botanics     Open Access   (Followers: 10)
Advances in Agronomy     Full-text available via subscription   (Followers: 11)
Advances in Life Science and Technology     Open Access   (Followers: 6)
AFBM Journal     Open Access  
Africa Development     Open Access   (Followers: 19)
Africa Research Bulletin: Political, Social and Cultural Series     Hybrid Journal   (Followers: 9)
African Journal of Agricultural Research     Open Access   (Followers: 3)
African Journal of Food Science     Open Access   (Followers: 5)
African Journal of Food, Agriculture, Nutrition and Development     Open Access   (Followers: 10)
African Journal of Horticultural Science     Open Access   (Followers: 2)
African Journal of Range & Forage Science     Hybrid Journal   (Followers: 5)
African Journal of Sustainable Development     Full-text available via subscription   (Followers: 7)
Agribusiness : an International Journal     Hybrid Journal   (Followers: 4)
Agricultura Tecnica     Open Access   (Followers: 6)
Agricultura Tropica et Subtropica     Open Access   (Followers: 2)
Agricultural Advances     Open Access   (Followers: 4)
Agricultural and Food Science     Open Access   (Followers: 21)
Agricultural Economics     Hybrid Journal   (Followers: 48)
Agricultural History     Full-text available via subscription   (Followers: 76)
Agricultural History Review     Full-text available via subscription   (Followers: 2)
Agricultural Research     Hybrid Journal   (Followers: 6)
Agricultural Science     Full-text available via subscription   (Followers: 6)
Agricultural Science     Open Access  
Agricultural Sciences     Open Access   (Followers: 8)
Agricultural Sciences in China     Full-text available via subscription   (Followers: 4)
Agricultural Systems     Hybrid Journal   (Followers: 22)
Agricultural Water Management     Hybrid Journal   (Followers: 19)
Agriculture     Open Access   (Followers: 7)
Agriculture & Food Security     Open Access   (Followers: 13)
Agriculture (Poľnohospodárstvo)     Open Access   (Followers: 1)
Agriculture and Agricultural Science Procedia     Full-text available via subscription   (Followers: 1)
Agriculture and Human Values     Hybrid Journal   (Followers: 12)
Agriculture, Ecosystems & Environment     Hybrid Journal   (Followers: 35)
Agriprobe     Full-text available via subscription  
Agriscientia     Open Access  
Agrivita : Journal of Agricultural Science     Open Access   (Followers: 4)
Agro-Science     Full-text available via subscription  
Agroalimentaria     Open Access   (Followers: 1)
Agrociencia     Open Access   (Followers: 2)
Agrokémia és Talajtan     Full-text available via subscription   (Followers: 1)
Agronomía Colombiana     Open Access   (Followers: 1)
Agronomía Costarricense     Open Access   (Followers: 2)
Agronomía Mesoamericana     Open Access   (Followers: 1)
Agronomie Africaine     Full-text available via subscription  
Agronomy     Open Access   (Followers: 8)
Agrosearch     Open Access  
AI & Society     Hybrid Journal   (Followers: 2)
Alinteri Zirai Bilimler Dergisi : Alinteri Journal of Agricultural Sciences     Open Access  
Ambiência     Open Access  
Ambiente & Agua : An Interdisciplinary Journal of Applied Science     Open Access   (Followers: 1)
American Journal of Agricultural and Biological Sciences     Open Access   (Followers: 10)
American Journal of Botany     Full-text available via subscription   (Followers: 14)
American Journal of Economics and Sociology     Hybrid Journal   (Followers: 24)
American Journal of Potato Research     Hybrid Journal   (Followers: 2)
American Journal of Rural Development     Open Access   (Followers: 1)
Anais da Academia Brasileira de Ciências     Open Access   (Followers: 2)
Annales des Sciences Agronomiques     Full-text available via subscription  
Annals of Agricultural and Environmental Medicine     Open Access   (Followers: 1)
Annals of Agricultural Sciences     Open Access   (Followers: 1)
Annual Review of Resource Economics     Full-text available via subscription   (Followers: 11)
APCBEE Procedia     Partially Free   (Followers: 2)
Applied Economics Letters     Hybrid Journal   (Followers: 22)
Applied Financial Economics Letters     Hybrid Journal   (Followers: 7)
Arboricultural Journal : The International Journal of Urban Forestry     Hybrid Journal   (Followers: 6)
Archivos de Zootecnia     Open Access   (Followers: 4)
Arquivos do Instituto Biológico     Open Access  
Arthropod-Plant Interactions     Hybrid Journal   (Followers: 1)
Asian Economic Papers     Hybrid Journal   (Followers: 3)
Asian Journal of Agricultural Research     Open Access   (Followers: 4)
Asian Journal of Plant Sciences     Open Access   (Followers: 2)
Australian Cottongrower, The     Full-text available via subscription   (Followers: 1)
Australian Economic Papers     Hybrid Journal   (Followers: 6)
Australian Economic Review     Hybrid Journal   (Followers: 7)
Australian Forest Grower     Full-text available via subscription   (Followers: 2)
Australian Forestry     Full-text available via subscription   (Followers: 4)
Australian Grain     Full-text available via subscription   (Followers: 5)
Australian Holstein Journal     Full-text available via subscription   (Followers: 2)
Australian Journal of Agricultural and Resource Economics     Hybrid Journal   (Followers: 6)
Australian Journal of Agricultural Engineering     Open Access   (Followers: 1)
Australian Sugarcane     Full-text available via subscription  
Avances en Investigacion Agropecuaria     Open Access   (Followers: 1)
Bangladesh Journal of Agricultural Research     Open Access   (Followers: 3)
Bangladesh Journal of Scientific Research     Open Access   (Followers: 1)
Berkala Ilmiah Pertanian     Open Access   (Followers: 1)
Bioagro     Open Access   (Followers: 1)
Biocatalysis and Agricultural Biotechnology     Hybrid Journal   (Followers: 5)
Biocontrol Science and Technology     Hybrid Journal   (Followers: 5)
Biodiversity     Hybrid Journal   (Followers: 25)
Biodiversity : Research and Conservation     Open Access   (Followers: 23)
Biological Agriculture & Horticulture : An International Journal for Sustainable Production Systems     Partially Free   (Followers: 12)
Biosystems Engineering     Hybrid Journal   (Followers: 1)

        1 2 3 4 5 | Last

Journal Cover   Cambridge Journal of Economics
  [SJR: 0.718]   [H-I: 47]   [22 followers]  Follow
    
   Hybrid Journal Hybrid journal (It can contain Open Access articles)
   ISSN (Print) 0309-166X - ISSN (Online) 1464-3545
   Published by Oxford University Press (OUP) Homepage  [339 journals]
  • Developing an understanding of meaningful work in economics: the case for
           a heterodox economics of work
    • Authors: Spencer; D. A.
      Pages: 675 - 688
      Abstract: The idea that work has meaning and is meaningful beyond its contribution to consumption has been largely absent from mainstream economics. This paper gives reasons for why mainstream economics has neglected the idea of meaningful work. It identifies the idea of the disutility of work, the assumption of free choice on the part of workers and the use of a formal and individualistic method as key constraints on the ability of mainstream economics to incorporate the idea of meaningful work. It also addresses the contribution of happiness economics and shows how it is unable to encompass the idea of meaningful work. Ideas on work from heterodox economics are then discussed. These ideas provide essential insight and inspiration for the incorporation of the idea of meaningful work into the economics of work. In all respects, the paper seeks to contribute towards the development and promotion of a heterodox economics of work that has the goal of meaningful work at its centre.
      PubDate: 2015-04-23T08:03:27-07:00
      DOI: 10.1093/cje/beu074
      Issue No: Vol. 39, No. 3 (2015)
       
  • Unpaid work and conformity: why care?
    • Authors: Della Giusta, M; Jewell, S.
      Pages: 689 - 710
      Abstract: We study the supply of unpaid eldercare (in particular caring for parents) in the UK, focusing on both the division of care and caring tasks by gender and the effect of conformity to social norms in relation to caring. We then investigate the effect of the amount of care on the well-being of caregivers and whether agreeing with the care norm enhances their well-being. Our results suggest that the eldercare reform neglects important aspects underlying the distribution of care hours and care tasks between caregivers and may potentially worsen intrahousehold inequality in earnings and well-being, in particular, between men and women.
      PubDate: 2015-04-23T08:03:27-07:00
      DOI: 10.1093/cje/beu061
      Issue No: Vol. 39, No. 3 (2015)
       
  • New Labour and work-time regulation: a Marxian analysis of the UK economy
    • Authors: Philp, B; Slater, G, Wheatley, D.
      Pages: 711 - 732
      Abstract: This article examines the impact of work-time regulation, introduced by the UK’s New Labour governments (1997–2010). In doing so, we return to Marx’s hypotheses regarding the length of the working day. These include the arguments that class conflict over the length of the working day is inherently distributional in a surplus-value sense and that workers often display a preference for reduced hours even with a proportionate reduction in pay. Our quantitative Marxist methodology provides a way of assessing the pattern of surplus value before and during the period of office of the New Labour governments and the distributional effects of regulation. The impact of such regulations on workers’ preferences are examined through an investigation of British Household Panel Survey data. Although many have been sceptical concerning the record of the last Labour governments, policies such as the Working Time Regulations (1998) and the Work-Life Balance Campaign (2000) are found to have been noteworthy innovations in the labour market. This is all the more important given recent moves by the successor government to weaken work-time regulation. Our results suggest the impact of these policy initiatives was broadly favourable, though the effect on men and women was different.
      PubDate: 2015-04-23T08:03:27-07:00
      DOI: 10.1093/cje/beu057
      Issue No: Vol. 39, No. 3 (2015)
       
  • The employment relationship in an (almost) structureless labour market:
           the case of domestic work
    • Authors: Suleman; F.
      Pages: 733 - 750
      Abstract: Although domestic workers are generally engaged in informal contracts with hourly and daily wages, some have formally written contracts and are paid monthly. Hourly and daily wages suggest flexible arrangements, whereas the monthly payment system may be used to develop a stable relationship. Using original data from a sample of domestic workers in Portugal, we offer empirical evidence on predictors of four types of arrangement that combine formality and stability. The results from multinomial logistic regression indicate that the wage level is a crucial predictor of the type of contract. Households seem to make a trade-off between stable contracts and high-level wages. However, the odds of being given a formal and stable contract increase when domestic workers have specific skills or are responsible for care, and there are trust-related issues. Our findings suggest that the use of flexible and informal labour has its limitations even in an activity perceived as non-skilled.
      PubDate: 2015-04-23T08:03:27-07:00
      DOI: 10.1093/cje/beu018
      Issue No: Vol. 39, No. 3 (2015)
       
  • Interlinkages between credit, debt and the labour market: evidence from
           Turkey
    • Authors: Karacimen; E.
      Pages: 751 - 767
      Abstract: This article examines workers’ use of credit in the context of a developing country, Turkey, based on empirical material collected through questionnaires and interviews with workers in the metal sector. The results provide evidence of a link between workers’ debt and the type of wage employment in two ways. First, I demonstrate that insecurity of employment and income is important in determining the increased tendency to borrow and increasing the vulnerability of workers to debt service problems. Second, I reveal that debt adds new dimensions to capital labour relations by functioning as a disciplining mechanism.
      PubDate: 2015-04-23T08:03:27-07:00
      DOI: 10.1093/cje/beu016
      Issue No: Vol. 39, No. 3 (2015)
       
  • Convergence of monetary equivalent of labour times (MELTs) in two Marxian
           interpretations
    • Authors: Akinci, U; Karahanogullari, Y.
      Pages: 769 - 781
      Abstract: This article is primarily concerned with a comparison of two different interpretations of the monetary equivalent of labour time (MELT), which is an essential category for the calculation of Marxian labour values. Beginning with a brief recap of these interpretations—temporal single system interpretation (TSSI) and the new interpretation (NI) of Duménil and Foley—the article emphasises the theoretical advantage of the TSS. Subsequently it refers to the second volume of Marx’s Capital to highlight the fundamental role of the concept of turnover in Marxian value theory and argues that for the calculation of the MELT, the appropriate level of abstraction should be the turnover of social capital rather than annual statistics. At that point, the article attempts to show theoretically and mathematically that whenever empirical calculations are made on the basis of social turnover data, the MELT of TSSI essentially converges to the MELT of the NI. However, the article also notes that this convergence cannot be interpreted as a substantial equivalence of these different theoretical approaches.
      PubDate: 2015-04-23T08:03:27-07:00
      DOI: 10.1093/cje/beu004
      Issue No: Vol. 39, No. 3 (2015)
       
  • Visible seeds of socialism and metamorphoses of capitalism: socialism
           after Rosdolsky
    • Authors: Motta e Albuquerque; E. d.
      Pages: 783 - 805
      Abstract: Roman Rosdolsky suggests a method to deal with the transition towards socialism that integrates three issues: 1) the identification of dynamic features of capitalism; 2) the systematisation of metamorphoses of capitalism; 3) the evaluation of how these metamorphoses reshape the elaboration of alternatives to capitalism. This evaluation is a precondition for the visualisation, within the complex dynamics of capitalism, of seeds of a new society—institutions born out of political struggles and of emancipatory features of key social processes. These institutions reshape the nature of the metamorphoses of capitalism and the possibility of establishing socialism and democracy.
      PubDate: 2015-04-23T08:03:27-07:00
      DOI: 10.1093/cje/beu050
      Issue No: Vol. 39, No. 3 (2015)
       
  • Early classics and Quesnay after Sraffa: a suggested interpretation
    • Authors: Cartelier; J.
      Pages: 807 - 824
      Abstract: The purpose of the article is to show how useful Sraffa’s formal scheme is for a critical study of classical economists in general and Quesnay’s Tableau économique in particular. Sraffa’s parsimonious argumentation offers a strong incentive to generalise his framework and suggest the idea of a classical system of prices whose prices of production would be a special case. To elaborate a clear notion of a classical system of prices relevant for the study of a priori different authors is the first objective of this article. In this view, the basic elements of a classical system of prices are distinguished: technique of production, rule of imputation of the price of surplus and conditions of reproduction. Even if this may help to have a fresh look on some authors like Petty or Cantillon, it is certainly (with the obvious exception of Ricardo and Torrens) about Quesnay and his Tableau économique that the idea of a classical system of prices is the most fruitful. To suggest a renewed reading of the Tableau is the second objective of the present article.
      PubDate: 2015-04-23T08:03:27-07:00
      DOI: 10.1093/cje/beu034
      Issue No: Vol. 39, No. 3 (2015)
       
  • The new Keynesian view of aggregate demand: some reflections from a
           classical-Sraffian standpoint
    • Authors: White; G.
      Pages: 825 - 842
      Abstract: The paper argues that the derivation of the aggregate demand curve in the new Keynesian literature is insufficient to provide the theoretical ground for the use to which it is usually put; namely, as a theoretical basis for the claim that long-run wage and price flexibility would push a capitalist economy to the full-employment or ‘natural’ level of output. It is argued that the derivation solely on the basis of the propositions about optimising household consumption expenditures is insufficient to guarantee a decreasing aggregate demand function without circular reasoning. This point is clarified by use of a very simple two-commodity production model of long-run steady states due to Spaventa and Nell. To guarantee a decreasing aggregate demand function, the new Keynesian approach must invoke the kinds of propositions used in more traditional derivations, propositions which themselves are in question on capital-theoretic grounds.
      PubDate: 2015-04-23T08:03:27-07:00
      DOI: 10.1093/cje/beu009
      Issue No: Vol. 39, No. 3 (2015)
       
  • What's in a name? Tony Lawson on neoclassical economics and heterodox
           economics
    • Authors: Morgan; J.
      Pages: 843 - 865
      Abstract: In this article I respond to Tony Lawson’s ‘What is this ‘School’ called neoclassical economics?’ Lawson’s paper is provocative because it reformulates neoclassical economics, based on Veblen’s original intent, as a mismatch created by recognising the value of an evolutionary approach to the economy whilst remaining over-reliant on elements of a ‘taxonomic’ approach. For Lawson many heterodox economists may be neoclassical under this description. I argue that there is clearly a case to be heard but that the reformulation of the neoclassical raises a number of issues. There are issues concerning the specific critique of the current usage of the term ‘neoclassical’—regarding genealogy and meaning. There are specific issues regarding the further development of the new (old Veblen) definition of the neoclassical: how clear is the definition in a practical context as a way to identify a ‘neoclassical group’, based on the commitments of the critique and the definition, what does it mean to be ‘more realistic’, and what is the strategic value of such a provocation for heterodoxy? I argue that the combination of these are reasons for more consideration of issues of social ontology not less insofar as the terms of the argument are incomplete, and this invites both Lawson and those he is criticising to progress the argument, particularly on method.
      PubDate: 2015-04-23T08:03:27-07:00
      DOI: 10.1093/cje/beu041
      Issue No: Vol. 39, No. 3 (2015)
       
  • Financialisation, income distribution and the crisis
    • Authors: Lang; D.
      Pages: 867 - 870
      PubDate: 2015-04-23T08:03:27-07:00
      DOI: 10.1093/cje/bev024
      Issue No: Vol. 39, No. 3 (2015)
       
  • The demands of finance and the glass ceiling of profit without investment
    • Authors: Cordonnier, L; Van de Velde, F.
      Pages: 871 - 885
      Abstract: In post-Keynesian recent works the ‘profit without investment’ case has made its appearance as a particular accumulation regime, one claiming along with two others (the contractive and the expansive case) that it can account for the different conceivable dynamic patterns at work in financialised capitalism. Actually, profit without investment—or rather, profit beyond investment—is in the very nature of capitalism. It is not a special case. The dividend channel is an essential component of profit formation. We show that its enabling condition, and what at the same time limits its width, is firms’ resort to debt. Beyond a certain point, the divorce between dividends and investment is such that firms’ policies leave their viable domain—a domain bounded by their wishes to be self-financing. Past that point, any increase in profits runs into a ‘glass ceiling’ in terms of outlets for those profits. It is when the demands of finance (i.e., of shareholders) reach this limit that the three regimes identified in the literature make their appearance, including the one called ‘profit without investment’. Seen in this light, these regimes are therefore all cases of profit without investment, ones that take on some reality and some plausibility when finance tries to drag profit without accumulation outside of its viable domain.
      PubDate: 2015-04-23T08:03:27-07:00
      DOI: 10.1093/cje/beu064
      Issue No: Vol. 39, No. 3 (2015)
       
  • Unemployment, working time and financialisation: the French case
    • Authors: Husson; M.
      Pages: 887 - 905
      Abstract: This article discusses the relationship between unemployment, working time and financialisation. I examine the French experience of working time reduction (the 35 hours week). I show that real wage growth has been frozen since the mid-1980s, working time reduction has been insufficient to create the amount of jobs necessary for maintaining full employment and most of the productivity gains were devoted to the recovery in the profit share. Under these conditions, we establish two important results. The first is that the rise in unemployment rate is offset by the increase in financialisation, measured as the difference between the profit share and the investment rate. The increase in dividends is therefore the counterpart of a lack in job creation due to an insufficient reduction of working time. The analysis has two main implications: growth is not a solution in itself, and the question of distribution is central, but it implies that capitalism should operate with a lower rate of profit, which it is not willing to accept.
      PubDate: 2015-04-23T08:03:27-07:00
      DOI: 10.1093/cje/bet051
      Issue No: Vol. 39, No. 3 (2015)
       
  • Finance-dominated capitalism and re-distribution of income: a Kaleckian
           perspective
    • Authors: Hein; E.
      Pages: 907 - 934
      Abstract: In this article a major channel through which financialisation or finance-dominated capitalism affects macroeconomic performance is examined: the distribution channel. Empirical data for the following dimensions of (re-)distribution in the period of finance-dominated capitalism since the early 1980s is provided for 15 advanced capitalist economies: functional distribution, personal/household distribution and the share and the composition of top incomes. Based on the Kaleckian approach to the determination of income shares, the effects of financialisation on functional income distribution are studied in more detail. Some stylised facts of financialisation are integrated into the Kaleckian approach, and by means of reviewing empirical and econometric literature it is found that financialisation and neoliberalism have contributed to the falling labour income share since the early 1980s through three main Kaleckian channels: 1) a shift in the sectoral composition of the economy, 2) an increase in management salaries and rising profit claims of the rentiers and thus in overheads, and 3) weakened trade union bargaining power.
      PubDate: 2015-04-23T08:03:27-07:00
      DOI: 10.1093/cje/bet038
      Issue No: Vol. 39, No. 3 (2015)
       
  • Rising inequality as a cause of the present crisis
    • Authors: Stockhammer; E.
      Pages: 935 - 958
      Abstract: The article argues that the economic imbalances that caused the present crisis should be thought of as the outcome of the interaction of the effects of financial deregulation with the macroeconomic effects of rising inequality. In this sense rising inequality should be regarded as a root cause of the present crisis. I identify four channels by which it has contributed to the crisis. First, rising inequality creates a downwards pressure on aggregate demand since poorer income groups have high marginal propensities to consume. Second, international financial deregulation has allowed countries to run larger current account deficits and for longer time periods. Thus, in reaction to potentially stagnant demand, two growth models have emerged: a debt-led model and an export-led model. Third, (in the debt-led growth models) higher inequality has led to higher household debt as working-class families have tried to keep up with social consumption norms despite stagnating or falling real wages. Fourth, rising inequality has increased the propensity to speculate as richer households tend to hold riskier financial assets than other groups. The rise of hedge funds and of subprime derivatives in particular has been linked to rise of the super-rich.
      PubDate: 2015-04-23T08:03:27-07:00
      DOI: 10.1093/cje/bet052
      Issue No: Vol. 39, No. 3 (2015)
       
  • Europe's Hunger Games: Income Distribution, Cost Competitiveness and
           Crisis
    • Authors: Storm, S; Naastepad, C. W. M.
      Pages: 959 - 986
      Abstract: The dominant view, both on the mainstream right and on the left, holds that the Eurozone crisis is a crisis of labour-cost competitiveness—with trade imbalances (and hence foreign indebtedness) being driven by divergences in relative unit labour costs (RULCs) between surplus and deficit countries. To re-balance Eurozone growth, the mainstream solution is a deflationary policy of ‘internal devaluation’ (i.e. cutting the wage share by as much as 30%) in the deficit countries. The ‘progressive’ view holds that the surplus countries should adjust by raising their wage shares. We argue that both sides of this debate are wrong and unhelpful. Europe’s trade imbalances are determined by domestic and world demand—whilst RULC divergences play only a negligible role. Eurozone growth can only be revived when Eurozone demand growth is restored, not by lowering wages here and/or raising them there. The current deflationary adjustment forced on the wage-led economies of Greece, Italy, Portugal and Spain is self-destructive: it is a ‘confidence killer’, not only deepening the free fall of southern European incomes but also damaging their productive base and productivity growth. The outlook is depressing—further increases in already high unemployment rates, inequality measures and poverty rates inconceivable in prosperous Europe just a few years ago—and arguably dystopian.
      PubDate: 2015-04-23T08:03:27-07:00
      DOI: 10.1093/cje/beu037
      Issue No: Vol. 39, No. 3 (2015)
       
 
 
JournalTOCs
School of Mathematical and Computer Sciences
Heriot-Watt University
Edinburgh, EH14 4AS, UK
Email: journaltocs@hw.ac.uk
Tel: +00 44 (0)131 4513762
Fax: +00 44 (0)131 4513327
 
About JournalTOCs
API
Help
News (blog, publications)
JournalTOCs on Twitter   JournalTOCs on Facebook

JournalTOCs © 2009-2015